Magazine Section
Reviews/Articles/Questions & Answers/Quotes:
Please submit your well written maximum three page article, review or event report: On Civil rights, human rights, economics, social welfare issues, environment,NGO operations [maximum one picture].It will be published here after peer review by 2 experts. Time to publish 10 to 60 days. We reserve right to reject any article without assigning any reason whatsoever. Only acceptance and publication will be acknowledged. You can send in famous quotes to be published here and your Questions about any issues and career questions. Send Articles in 'word' format with Arial 12 points font to : Liberties_forum@rediffmail.com
HIGH INTEREST RATE REGIME AND MICROFINANCE ISSUES [Prof R.K Gupta on 20-1-2011]
In India the interests are too high.In fact in Islamic countries they have very prudent norms for interest.USA is presently having near zero rates.The result is that portfolio of Sharia compliant companies are doing study and much better than general pool of companies.There has to be ethics in business and no exploitation be allowed in garb of capitalism, liberalisation and 'what market bears' concept.Markets are not ideal and free from cartel's and consumers are not capable to defend and decide. Regulations are must. Mr Singh must take a refresher course as he has been responsible for letting loose financial madness and big loot in the country since he has taken over as PM; Or else he must quit. We don't need his fraudulent expertise and hinesty. He is a big failure. In any case he is toothless tiger that has again become evident by meaningless reshuffle of cabinet to fool people that some thing is happening.
We don't favor interest rates i. e PLR more than 5 % pa and maximum commercial borrowing rate including personal loans at 12%.
For microfinance we can allow 5% more for high service cost and bad debts. So they can be allowed up to 17%
It is fallacy to assume that by raising interest rates by 1/2 % or 1% prices will come down in economy now. Not at all. In fact prices will go up again as working capital costs goes up in supply chain. It is time MM Singh, Mukherjee and other guys in Government understand this truth and come out of their stupor and self imposed arrogance.
Microfinance is very important to NGOs as these are directly linked to enabling poor and developing livelihood means in society. But microfinance companies like SKS microfinance ( An American stooge promoted company) started charging huge rates and indulge in extra-legal means to extract instalments. They were also doing overselling.
All this must end and above suggested rates should be brought in economy.
We reject the Malegam report submitted on microfinance companies working. Though some good points have been suggested in it.
What GOI has to do is tone up our legal system and make recovery of loans and civil money decrees more time bound and stringent so people cant escape from paying back liabilities and be put in jails. The inefficiency of legal system is reflected in high cost of loans. This is precisely the reason Citibank charges huge rate of interest like 40% on overdue credit card payments. It is sheer loot. The corrupt politicians are blind to this all as they favor MNCs and greedy capitalists.
The transcript of interview of CNBC with Mr Vijay Mahajan of BASIX on the report is also reproduced below for discussions by members:
Suggestions are welcome
------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
The long awaited Malegam report on microfinance companies was submitted today. The committee has recommended that MFIs charge no more than 24% on loans and that the margins they make be also no more than 10%. The committee has recommended the creation of a separate category of MFIs called NBFC-MFIs. These NBFCs can give loans only to families whose total income is not more than Rs 50,000 per annum, and largely for income generation purposes.
In an interview with CNBC-TV18, Vijay Mahajan, Founder, BASIX and Chairman, MFIN, speaks about the report and gives his outlook going forward.
Excerpts from India Business Hour on CNBC-TV18 Watch the full show »
Here is a verbatim transcript of the exclusive interview with Vijay Mahajan on CNBC-TV18. Also watch the accompanying video.
Q: What is your reaction to the various findings and the recommendations made by Mr Malegam?
A: The Malegam committee report is a very good step forward to the whole controversy about microfinance institutions, particularly non-bank finance companies doing micro finance because that comes under RBI purview. So, the report has very clearly recognized the legitimate role of NBFCs and micro finance and has recommended new category of NBFCs for micro finance. While defining that category it has given several parameters, firstly 90% of all assets other than cash should be in micro finance loans and micro finance loans have been defined as no more than Rs 25000 per individual. So that’s actually half of what it has been earlier, but this is fine I think for the poorer states. It would be a bit on the lower side, particularly for Southern Indian states and Western Indian states. Nevertheless it’s a good beginning.
There is also an upper limit of the number of MFIs, no more than two can lend to a single borrower, with the total amount remaining Rs 25000 and there is a requirement that MFIs should use the credit information bureau. Most important restriction is on interest rates. The interest rate has been capped at 24% which is what most large MFIs had already adopted in the last few months. Also, the margins have also been capped, that is no more than 10% over the borrowing rate for smaller MFIs. In addition, up to a 1% processing fee has been agreed on. If insurance has been provided, that can be charged separately. So, the report recognizes the legitimate role for providing insurance services.
Q: One of the findings of the report suggest that last year the interest charged by the larger MFIs range between 31% to 51%, roughly averaging to 37%. Now, the report suggests a cap of 24% on interest rates that are charged by MFIs on individual loans. So, in that context, will this cap come as a hindrance on MFIs that are lending? If implemented, to what extent can this 24% level actually impact MFI functioning?
A: If you read the report just couple of pages ahead of where you quoted from, specifically para 7.6.3A, there is a correction on this figure that the report itself mentions. They have said that they have not taken into account the assigned portfolio for the purpose of calculating the interest. So, really speaking the interest rate that they have stated is overstated between 20-25% of the interest amount which means that if they are saying 36% it’s actually closer to about 28-29% which we all were indeed in the range of.
So, with that correction what will happen is that at 24% cap, those MFIs which were making exceptionally high returns on assets in the range of 5-7%, they will now probably not be able to make it, whereas those who are in the range of 3-4% would continue to do so. Indeed for its own competitions the Malegam committee has assumed a return on equity which is about 22%. So, I think they are quite conscious of the fact that the sector will require capital and capital has to come from investors and investors are looking for return on equity. So, it’s a very balanced approach to the whole process. They have not consigned the field to the basket of charity or subsidy. They have said do it, do it in a sustainable way, but also do not do it in a manner which is exploitative or over charges the customers.
Article 01/11/policy 25/06/2011
(Prof R K Gupta -25-06-2011)
India is very badly and loosely regulated country and fraudulent democracy with people having no power except to caste a vote once in 5 years. This is being abused by one and all in any power.
1.Install Jan Lokpal (public Protection officer) at center who has powers to start investigation, monitoring, data collection, scrutinizing documents and files related to a matter, prosecution and penalizing and recommending impeachment, disqualifying or dismissal of politicians and bureaucrats and judges and annex their properties to national treasury except for :
President of India
Chief Justice of India
Army Chief
Solicitor General of India
and Comptroller and Auditor General of India
He can also direct any official to dispose off a pending application/case in a given time framework.
He can also direct government or private detective agencies and banking system, income tax and revenue intelligence department to trace and compile wealth and properties of any government functionaries including judges and their own family members.
There is too much fuss created for Prime Minister post. In our view Prime minister is just another minister and mainly responsible for ethical working of central government and hence cant be excluded.
However Lokpal should only control corruption and malpractices
( Mere monitory corruption is not enough-delays and harassment is also a kind of corruption)charges and suspicions about class I officers and political positions in country at state and central levels. Not at district levels. His area should also include corporate frauds with public and governments.
The Lokpal order can be reviewed only once by a panel of CAGI,CJI and Vice President of India so that any abuse may not take place. This should be disposed in maximum 90 days period.
Lokpal can be removed only by impeachment in both houses of parliament. His term should be 5 years and not renewable. Lokpal will be non political person and a known expert. A penal of 50 nominated or self nominated persons after preliminary screening of non bureaucrats and non political persons can be put in national portal and poll invited from people for 3 months period. The top 5 can be reviewed by a panel of President of India, CJI and Chief election commissioner of India for final choice.
2.All lokpals and Governors should be non-political people
3.Police chiefs of States should report to governors for their service matters and complaints against and not State ministry who can have only functional control. Any order of state government can be declined by Police Chief of state or Additional Director General and above level and a note explaining reason can be sent to Governor.
For example the order of mid night lathi charge in Ram lila Maidan was patently illegal act and uncalled for and Delhi police commissioner should have declined to execute it.
4.For district level control, a citizens council should be setup which will have similar controls on district level officials up to collector and IG level and chairmen of local bodies. This panel may contain up to 10 members selected from non political personalities from bar council, judges, NGO presidents and academicians. They should have powers up to dismissal and to direct officials to complete pending task in given time period. Till now babus report only to their seniors who are in turn corrupt and not free to take action.
5. Demonetize Rs 1000 currency notes immediately (within span of 3 months ) as these are no longer required. Indian banking system and credit debit card systems are now well developed up to village level.
Rs 500 Note is enough to run cash retail business for common man.
American paper currency comes in seven denominations: $1, $2, $5, $10, $20, $50, and $100. The United States no longer issues $500, $1,000, $5,000, and $10,000 bills. But they are still legal tender and may still be in circulation
6. Government should ask all politicians holding public posts as state and central ministers and chairmen etc and judges of high court to disclose property and deposits held abroad in their own name and names of their own family members in overseas banks. If not found legitimate these should be confiscated. Any amounts found beyond disclosed amounts should be asked to be frozen by banks in other countries and recovered.
7. Have "No candidate" provision in ballot papers (NOTA) . If 20 % of voters in a constituency opt for this, then re-nomination of all candidates be called for. This will remove all bad elements from elections system.
Make 30% of polled votes compulsory for any party to form government. If less than this ratio, a mixed government should be formed as per strength in house of various parties/independent candidates.
8.State funding of election expenses and complete ban on donations by candidates to parties for election tickets.
9. Enact public services delivery and accountability act. All government officials should be made accountable to deliver sanctions, services and aides etc within a specified time frame. After which it will be automatically approved. If any officer is found to have 5 defaults in a year, he should be dismissed from service. For every default a ticket should be put in his service file and be considered along with public complaints for increments, promotions and continuing service after first 10 years and 20 years of completed service.
Government jobs are not charity posts for life and foul conduct.
10 Reduce or eliminate various taxes in India including income tax and start transaction taxes and expenditure taxes for amounts above Rs 10,000.All these transactions must have PAN number or UID or defense services enrolment number. Reduce stamp duty and other charges on property transaction to 5% so that black money generation in real estate is stopped.
11.Put property ceiling for individuals and companies to stop hoarding of land and building by corrupt babus politicians and businessmen. India has no land and no one should possess excessive and not required land and buildings. many Industrialists have got allotted huge land without any use.
Make rental laws fair to both parties and evacuation of tenants easier so that lot of property comes in market. India should promote with tax concessions and subsidy housing and low cost shops running companies forming a national corpus of 1 lac crores to start with.
12.Amend prevention of corruption act to prosecute spouse ( as they are always beneficiary of loot) and life imprisonment a punishment and 10 times fine for amount involved. Withdrawal of all service benefits and instant dismissal. Only one appeal be allowed by a session level court to be disposed off in maximum 2 years time.
Start relieving babus and judges after every 10 years of service after reviewing complaints against them, performance and behavior and medial fitness. Every year 4% of babudom and judges should be removed so as to create fear and also give chance to new blood. Civil servces rules have to be drastically changed with lateral entry by experts with 10 years professional experience. Scrap UPSC.
13.Start national portal for citizens satisfaction surveys, consumer surveys and opinion polls on performance of various political posts and class one officers. This will expose bad officers and politicians and also show them their popularity ratings. Specially prime minister and CMs. If a satisfaction survey is conducted for police department, they are likely to get not even 5 marks out of 100.
14.Set up a special revenue intelligence Board with government and non governmental experts to monitor and question foreign deposits and outflows by various individuals, officials and companies. And to take action to recover assets.
15.India should now change laws to align with UN convention on corruption.
16.Start pensions and social security for all citizens after 55 years of age and pension to be 40% of last gross salary drawn when retiring voluntary or having lost jobs. This to be adjusted for inflation every three years period. If unemployed or fresh person then a sum of Rs 2500 per month can be given for a renewable period of 12 months every time and 3000 to senior citizens above age of 65 eyars who do not have taxable incomes
17.Only two terms of 5 years for all political positions in India.
18.Enact professional services act to control malpractices ,delays overcharging and corruption and harassment by lawyers, CAs and such professionals like independent doctors, consultants lawyers engineers and architects.
19 If state fails to protect the person and property and dignity of a citizen and fails to prosecute the accused then state compensation should be given as per status of person subject to maximum of Rs 50 lacs. The concerned officials who defaulted should be penalized for this and their service record tagged (Example a SHO fails to file challan even after 2 years period)
The above suggestions are moderate and as first steps and can be implemented easily if government actually wants. No excuses please.
People should demand these actions or remove government. Enough is enough.
**************************************************************************************************************
Corporate Retail: Dangerous Implications for India's Economy
Shankar Gopalakrishnan and Priya Sreenivasa
Unseen by most, celebrated by some and condemned by others, a quiet transformation is beginning to shape significant parts of India's economy. This is the penetration and expansion of what is often called “organised retail” or “modern retail”, though “corporate retail” would be the more accurate term. Those who support corporate retail have argued that this is a positive development, one that will lead to a sea change in the conditions of consumption and production in India. It will herald lower prices, more choice, less wastage and economic growth.
We argue here that this positive picture is a misrepresentation. The growth of corporate retail not only will not address the key problems plaguing India's economy today – it will greatly exacerbate many of them. In particular, the crisis in agriculture, environmental destruction, declines in land productivity, urban unemployment, price volatility and unequal access to resources would all be worsened by unchecked growth of corporate retail. In this context, Commerce Minister Kamal Nath's announcement of effectively revised FDI norms should be a matter of concern. This article focuses on food retail, the subject of most of the debate.
Arguments of Supporters of Corporate Retail
Proponents of corporate retail typically rely on a few main arguments. First, “consumers” and “farmers” will benefit; second, the impact on existing retailers and hence no employment will be minimal or controllable; and, third, the negative impact (if any) will only be on intermediaries. A good example of these arguments is the Indian Council for Research in International Economic Relations' (ICRIER) study on the issue (Joseph et al 2008), which was commissioned by the government for the purpose of studying the impact of corporate retail. Other examples include studies by Kumar et al (2008) and by Mukherjee and Patel (2005).
The claims regarding gains to “consumers” are the main plank of the argument. The ICRIER study claims consumers will gain from lower prices, more choices, better and more consistent quality, convenience and hygiene. They will also gain from a “better shopping experience.” All of these points except the last are traced to corporate retailers' tendency to build consolidated supply chains. The elimination of middlemen is regarded as key to quality improvements and lower prices.
“Farmers”, it is said, will also gain from the elimination of middlemen. They will receive higher prices for their produce and will have a better understanding of demand (Mukherjee and Patel 2005). The involvement of large corporates, particularly in contract farming arrangements, will enable farmers to access better technology and inputs. Investment in infrastructure by corporates will reduce wastage.
Other existing retailers, particularly the kirana stores, handcart vendors, hawkers, etc., are acknowledged to suffer from the entry of corporate retail, but such impact is regarded as temporary and and relatively minor. It is argued that the retail market will expand sufficiently for both types of retailers to co-exist. Small retailers are said to be more accessible, to have better knowledge of their consumers, and to be able to offer credit. These advantages will ensure that they survive in a market where “there will be space for everyone.” Further, any loss of employment would be canceled out by the growth in jobs due to corporate retailers, which the ICRIER study describes as “high quality” employment.
As for intermediaries, it is accepted that intermediaries may suffer a negative impact (as would be in keeping with the elimination of middlemen, which is seen as an advantage). But, as with small retailers, any resulting loss of employment would be canceled out by the expansion of the market.
Problems with Pro-Corporate Retail Arguments
These arguments suffer from three key conceptual problems. First, the arguments are built around certain terms – particularly “farmer”, “kirana store”, and “consumer” - that are used as if they refer to homogeneous categories with common interests. The class and social contradictions within these categories are ignored and, in each case, the definition slips towards equating high income or socially powerful elements with the entirety of the category. Thus the ICRIER study divides “consumers” into five categories, of which the lowest (described as “low income”) corresponds to a monthly income of Rs. 10,000 or less. Thus “low income” would include the majority of urban residents (leave alone the rural population), while the other four categories would be a minority. Similarly, among “farmers”, the assumption is made that all farmers produce primarily for the market and have access to capital and infrastructure. The ICRIER study relies on a single sample study of 197 farmers in Hoskote, near Bangalore, who are clearly well-off cash crop cultivators with a high degree of infrastructure (having an average landholding of more than 4 acres, an average of 51% of land area under irrigation, and all cultivating cauliflowers). The conclusions from this sample are generalised to all “farmers” in the country.
Second, it is argued that corporate retailers will provide lower prices to consumers and higher prices to farmers. But this rests on the belief that corporate retailers will be subject to a market with perfect competition, a highly unlikely reality that is again belied by empirical evidence from elsewhere (see below). This reality is rarely engaged with, and when it is, unrealistic assumptions are made (for instance, Kumar et al (2008) choose simply to believe that the 'benefits' from elimination of middlemen will be equally shared by farmers, retailers and consumers).
Third, the ICRIER study and other studies assume an enormous expansion of the retail market which will “make space for everyone.” The ICRIER study predicts this on the basis of calculations whose details are not given, while Kumar et al (2008) do so simply on the basis of GDP growth. But, in regard to food retail (which is the main focus of these two studies), it is well known that, beyond a certain minimal income level, food consumption becomes increasingly inelastic with income increases. This is particularly true of an economy where GDP growth is unequally distributed and most gains are being captured by urban elites. In this context, market expansion of foods (if it occurs at all) most likely reflects increased consumption of luxury items and processed foods by these elites, which in turn is unlikely to "make space" for non-corporate retailers.
These conceptual problems seriously undermine the analysis of empirical data in such studies. They also prevent us from engaging with corporate retail's impact on social dynamics, which are entirely erased from the picture by such stereotyped categorizations.
Conceptual Approach
The conceptual approach that we take here differs from the above, in that we argue that corporate retail should not be considered a different type of retail alone. Instead, the concept of a “system of provision” advanced by Fine and Leopold (1993) is more useful. From this perspective, the notion of “consumer sovereignty” - namely the stereotyping of “consumer demand” in the literature on FDI in retail – is entirely inadequate, given that it views consumers without considering any of the social, political, class and historical factors that shape consumption and its determinants. Rather, consumer demand and attitudes, production processes, and supply and distribution systems are all linked to each other in a dialectical fashion. The result is a complex interaction between production, supply, retail sale and consumption, a chain of activities which shapes not only the final commodity but also the social and cultural environment in which it is consumed. This is described as a “system of provision” - “the inclusive chain of activity that attaches consumption to the production that makes it possible” (Fine 2002).
It is our argument that corporate retail is more accurately viewed as one face of a different system of provision. This is a crucial change in emphasis, for in this view, corporate retailers and their strategies, for good or for bad, cannot be seen in isolation. In the case of food, the entire existing food system and the corporate food system must be examined together to understand the processes that are taking place. In the existing food system in India, production, distribution and retail are dominated by 'small' actors, ranging from marginal farmers through traders and retailers. Each of these actors operates in one niche of a complex network of institutions, including those regulated by the state (such as the wholesale mandis) and those regulated by social institutions, such as gender, caste and community. Moreover, food consumption may also take place through non-market mechanisms, particularly in the case of the dependence of marginal farmers on consumption of their own produce.
Due to changes induced by liberalization, however, it has now become possible for large corporates to directly take control of practically the entire system of provision. This 'control' is exercised, first, by appropriating and 'industrializing' agricultural production; second, by displacing the existing trading system and replacing it with arms of the capital concerned; and, finally, by the entry of corporate food retail. Together, these changes ensure that the production and exchange system as a whole is transformed, producing the results now seen as characteristic of corporate retail. This does not require that a single company own every aspect of the system of provision. What is required is that decisions over production, distribution and sale are shaped by a concentration of capital – a corporate or set of corporates - and their interaction with the system's other actors. It should be noted that while this contextualizes the retail operation, it does not diminish its importance. It is only through control over retail that there can be full control over commodity prices, and hence the fact that such systemic transformations frequently seem to 'begin' from the retail end.
This perspective is discussed in greater detail in Sreenivasa (2007). In this article, we attempt to briefly explore the changes in class and social relations that corporate system of food provision produce, and to consider the potential impacts of such changes in the Indian context.
Corporate Food Systems and Agriculture
At the production level, the transition to a corporate food system revolves essentially around one key change: a reliance on contract farming. Studies from countries as diverse as Vietnam (Cadilhon et al 2006), China (Hu et al 2004), Argentina (Gutman 2002 and Ghezan et al 2002), Chile (Faigenbaum et al 2002), Brazil (Farina 2002), South Africa (Oxfam 2004) and India (Chandrasekhar and Ghosh \1; Daftari 2006) indicate the preference of corporates for contract farming. Such contracts typically involve guaranteed purchases, quality standards, exclusive contracts that prevent sale to other entities, and frequent use of verbal and unrecorded contracts (Oxfam 2004).
Contract farming is frequently argued to benefit farmers. Guaranteed purchase ensures more stable prices, while access to technical knowledge and physical inputs is increased (Cadilhon et al 2006). But contract farming also has inbuilt structural features that have negative impacts for all producers, and differential impacts depending on the producers' class position.
The first such feature is the transfer of power over production decisions to the corporate purchaser, particularly through the imposition of private quality standards. This hardly seems objectionable prima facie, but in actuality has several implications. Standards, firstly, may revolve around “quality” as defined by the corporate's needs (for instance, larger, redder apples that are visually attractive, or produce that is less likely to spoil), rather than “quality” in the nutritional or consumer sense. The producer frequently has to make additional investments to meet these standards, investments that may not be socially positive in the sense they are often assumed to be. Second, the imposition of stringent quality standards results in rejection of produce; non-purchase on quality grounds is the most often cited complaint of producers against contract farming, and it significantly diminishes any gain from secure prices[1]. Quality standards also often specify the fertilizer inputs, seeds, and production methods to be used (see Ghezan et al 2002 and Hu et al 2004 for examples).
Linked to quality standards are demands for “flexible” production, driven by the desire to reduce inventory costs. “Flexibility” can mean changes in the quantity of crop demanded, delivery at a certain time of day or month, or new and sometimes risky crops, with the risk of failure being borne by the cultivator (Shepard 2005). Companies tend also to steadily increase demands, often later making additional demands for producers to also engage in preliminary processing (such as cutting or packing) (see Cadilhon et al 2006; Boselie et al 2004; Dev and Rao 2005).
A second feature is the increase in capital and input intensity of agriculture. Higher levels of fertilisers, pesticides, water and mechanization shorten production time and reduce natural risks such as pest attacks. They also allow 'fine tuning' of production based on changing corporate standards. Further, cropping patterns under contract farming shift towards fresh fruits, vegetables and cash crops such as cut flowers, which offer higher margins on final sale and are seen as 'advantageous' for various reasons (see Sreenivasa 2007; Oxfam 2004). The result can be seen in, for example, the Kuppam Agricultural Pilot Project (KAPP) in Andhra Pradesh, which was set up at a cost of Rs. 5.7 lakhs per acre - roughly ten times the investment made by even rich farmers in the area (Chandrasekhar and Ghosh 2003). Similarly, 15,000 kg of fertilizer was applied to each hectare of land in contract rose cultivation in Karnataka (Singh 2005). This increase in inputs has serious ecological consequences, which can be ignored by the contracting corporate as it is not bound to a particular patch of land. This has led Sharma (2004) to describe contract farming as modern day “slash and burn agriculture”.
A third feature is interlocking of agreements on credit, inputs and extension services (Singh 2005). FoodWorld in India, for instance, reportedly supplies its contracted farmers with seeds and fertilizer from allied companies on credit; default on these loans would lead to FoodWorld withdrawing from purchase (Shepard 2005). Such cartelization further decreases the autonomy of the producer.
A fourth feature is delays in payment to producers, a near universal practice. Contract purchasers frequently delay payment by a month or two, in order to speculate on market demand and to invest customer revenues before making payments. This amounts to an implicit subsidy to the corporate from the producer. For instance, as one South African report put it, “[The delay in payments] has been claimed was the critical break-through in constructing the supermarket industry in South Africa as this means that super marketers can sell goods at low market but in mass volume terms and rely on the extended time to pay the price for the goods they have received” (NALEDI 2001). These factors are all the more salient in times of high inflation (Gutman 2002).
The net result of these changes is to transfer risk to the producer while transferring control to the corporate. The risk of production failure is transferred through the quality standards mechanism, the risk of fertility loss is transferred by the nature of contracts themselves, and the risk of demand fluctuations is transferred through the delay in payments. These structures are complemented by more straightforward abuses of power. The latter includes retrospectively imposing the costs of discounts, product promotions, etc on producers (Gutman 2002). In the UK, suppliers have found themselves being asked “to pay a fee just to be listed as a supplier; pay another fee to get shelf space; ... contribute to nominated charities; give a profit contribution to boost the supermarket's own earnings; and pay for product promotions” (Oxfam 2004). Examples of problems in India include post facto lowering of prices, delays in payment, defaults on contracts when the market was in a glut (including by Pepsi), as well as contractual clauses allowing the companies to refuse to purchase the crop - while penalizing farmers for default (Kumar et al 2005; Singh 2005). In Andhra Pradesh, corporates tended to initially have lax contract conditions to draw in farmers and then tightened the conditions over time (Dev and Rao 2005).
This change in control and risk has differing impacts for different classes of farmers. If we utilize the fourfold division of productive cultivators commonly used in analyses of Indian agriculture[2], we can approach the problem as follows. Capitalist farmers, who rely on hired labor and mechanization and are able to retain a surplus for reinvestment in agriculture, are the most likely to benefit from contract farming. Studies from Argentina found that contract farming worked well for potato producers in the 250 hectare to 400 hectare range (Ghezan et al 2002), while among Brazil's dairy producers, the top 5.3% were able to invest in the technology necessary for supplying corporate dairy outlets (Farina 2002). Yet even such producers are likely to face problems from increased risks and high investment requirements.
For rich and middle peasants, namely those who are net hirers of labour and cultivate primarily for the market, contract farming can be far more difficult. The required investment, higher labor intensity and greater infrastructure are difficult and sometimes impossible for such farmers (Shepard 2005; see Farina 2002; Ghezan et al 2002; Gutman 2002; Cadilhon et al 2006; etc. for examples). Yet interest levels among such farmers are often initially high, since guaranteed purchases appear attractive. Hence, internationally, one finds that the number of suppliers for corporate food procurement is large at the beginning and then falls rapidly as many are weeded out. For instance, in Brazil, from 1997 – 2000 the number of dairy producers supplying the top 12 companies fell by 35%, while the size of the average supplier increased by 55% (Farina 2002). Those left out face other consequences. The diminished offtake of traditional wholesalers can result in market saturation and falls in prices (e. g potato and horticultural production in Argentina [Ghezan et al 2002]). In more mechanised segments, such producers can be excluded from the market entirely; also in Argentina, the number of dairy farms fell from 40,000 in 1983 – around the time when corporate transformation of the supply chain began - to 15,000 in 2001 (Gutman 2002).
Marginal farmers, the majority in India, engage in a qualitatively different relationship with the market. Produce is generally consumed by the family, with only the surplus (if any) sold in order to meet debts, purchase needed commodities, access health care and so on. The additional capital and the concentrated risks of contract farming would both be impossibilities for members of this class. Hence as the corporate food system expands and the traditional procurement system shrinks (see below), the market access of such producers itself is likely to reduce. This, in turn, would accelerate their reliance on hiring out their labor as the only means of a cash income. Moreover, declines in cultivation of food crops in areas with heavy contract farming can lead to volatility of food prices, harming these peasants further, as they tend to be net purchasers of food (Chandrasekhar and Ghosh 2003). Expansion in contract farming and the resulting more rapid differentiation can lead to such producers being driven off the land entirely; in Karnataka, large-scale leases in one district for contract rose cultivation resulted in takeover of land from SC's and ST's, who (given the small number of lessees and hence an oligopolistic market) received a lease rate approximately one third the market price (Singh 2005).
The impact is also harsh for the 'other' agricultural class, namely agricultural labour. This section is ignored by most discussions of corporate food systems, but available data indicates that it is not likely to gain from contract farming. Labour intensity may increase as the cropping area devoted to crops such as fruits and vegetables rises. But this does not necessarily mean greater employment, as it may involve mechanisation as well, and further the increased entry of marginal producers into the labour market may cancel any positive effect. In terms of contract production itself, a detailed study by Oxfam (2004) on working conditions in global agricultural supply chains describes severe insecurity of contracts, ever-increasing demands on workers for overtime, and repression of worker rights. It may be objected that this is nothing unusual for agricultural labour, particularly in India. But corporate food production intensifies this in a different manner, for it leads to increased pressure on producers to produce more and to be more “flexible”, and the best, at times the only, option for cost reduction is greater exploitation of workers. Hence reports have noted an increasing reliance on women and migrant workers, who are easier to control (Oxfam 2004; Chandrasekhar and Ghosh 2003). The use of migrant workers in the KAPP and in contract farming in Punjab led to wages being pushed down to subsistence level (Chandrasekhar and Ghosh 2003).
In sum, rather than being a panacea for Indian agriculture, corporate food production will likely accelerate many key elements of India's agricultural crisis. It will produce a decline in land productivity, reduce food security, adversely affect price stability (also see below) and will tend to negatively impact employment and credit relations. The usual remedy recommended in this regard is public assistance and the formation of cooperatives for “small” farmers (which category often reduces to all cultivators who are not capitalist farmers). But such assistance can only mitigate, not reverse, the negative tendencies of corporate food production, and does not address wider questions of employment, sustainability and food security. Moreover, this begs the question – if the state has such capabilities and is so accountable to small and marginal producers, why not form cooperatives up to the retail level? Why turn to corporate retail at all? Indeed, why do we have an agricultural crisis in the first place?
Procurement, Distribution and Processing
Since control over producers and transfer of risk is a key part of a corporate system of provision, the intermediate supply chain has to be transformed in order to achieve these goals. Thus, once a certain minimum size is crossed, corporate systems usually switch to a centralised procurement system (Reardon et al 2003). This usually means a single or few purchasing hubs, which receive the produce, allocate it to retail outlets and handle major packaging and processing tasks. As the logistics chain is developed, this shift tends to occur first in non-perishable goods such as processed and dry foods, and later enter fresh foods (Hu et al 2004). Such systems diminish waste, allow the corporate to tightly control the characteristics of the product, and permit minimising inventory in perishable items while holding stock for speculative purposes in non-perishable goods.
As a result of such changes, existing wholesalers and intermediaries tend to be replaced by “specialised” wholesalers, who focus on a single product or group of products, and “dedicated” wholesalers, who contract with a single corporate for procurement and provision of goods (Reardon et al 2003; Shepard 2005). For instance, between 2000 and 2003, the reliance of two Chinese chains on specialised wholesalers rose from 25% to 75% of their procurement; while in Thailand, each of the hypermarket chains in Manila relies on just one accredited wholesaler of fruits and vegetables (Hu et al 2004; Shepard 2005). The 'new' wholesalers enforce quality standards, provide packaging and processing services, and in the case of “dedicated” wholesalers develop new product lines specific to that particular corporate.
Thus retail and wholesale functions gradually become integrated under a single corporate (which usually enters as a retailer, but may also enter at the wholesale level). Over time the category of “wholesaler” is eliminated; in South Africa, which has an older corporate food system than most of the developing world, “The notion that wholesalers are a distinct category in the commodity chain is one that has been superseded since the 1980's” (NALEDI 2001). Wholesalers and retailers often undertake corporate mergers (Shepard 2005).
Corporate food systems also involve an increase in the degree of processing, for a number of reasons. First, inherent to the corporate system is an ever-increasing need for flexibility in storage time, allowing the corporate to more effectively match demand fluctuations. This leads to increased “preservation, preparation and packaging” (Fine and Leopold 1993); for instance, dairy sectors in Latin America saw considerably higher levels of investment in packaging and preservatives (Gutman 2002; Farina 2002). Second, there is a contradictory need to both capture larger market share by introducing new “choices”, while simultaneously maintaining economies of scale. The result is product differentiation through increased second stage processing, rather than through varying the actual source foods. This increases “choice” at one level, but decreases choce at another. For instance, corporate agribusiness is known to accelerate the tendency towards declining crop diversity and the abandonment of many species and strains of foodgrains, in favour of a few 'standard' strains of "mainstream" grains.
Investment in processing and infrastructure is often regarded as one of the advantages of corporate food systems. This is no doubt true with respect to spoilage and infectious diseases. But it can also have reverse effects. Using large quantities of preservatives, for instance, is hardly conducive to better health and can be very dangerous. As Fine and Leopold (1993) put it, there is no intrinsic difference between using additives and adulterating food – both aim at reducing costs, increasing shelf life and, frequently, enticing consumers. What defines their distinction is only the shifting terrain of law.
Meanwhile, there are several socioeconomic impacts from these changes. The first is the displacement of existing wholesalers and traders. Only a few such traders with sufficient capital and size are able to transform themselves (Shepard 2005). A survey in Chile showed “massive displacement of small traders” (Faiguenbaum et al 2002). In Argentina, the country's largest wholesale fruit market witnessed a 50% fall in market share between the mid 1980's and the 1990's. In China, there was a negative correlation between traditional wholesalers and the spread of supermarket chains (Hu et al 2004).
A second impact is consolidation among food processors. Experiences in both Argentina and Brazil show increased concentration among dairy processing units as small firms and cooperatives disappeared (Gutman 2002; Farina 2002). In Chile, smaller meat slaughterhouses were driven out of business by increased imports through corporate retailers and wholesalers (Faiguenbaum et al 2002). The overall result is an increase in oligopsony and oligopolies among processors.
A third impact is increased price volatility and speculation. Contract farming increases this tendency, as noted above, given the delay in payments to producers and the demand for “flexibility.” Thus, in the US, supermarkets raised tomato prices by 46% between 1994 and 2004, even as real prices paid to producers fell by 25% (Oxfam 2004). In addition, corporate systems are able to integrate far better with global trade; as noted above, corporate retailers in Chile imported around 40% to 80% of meat products sold (Faiguenbaum et al 2002).
In India, the small spread of corporate systems has as yet made such impacts less visible. However, amendments to the Agricultural Produce Marketing Committee (APMC) Acts to allow for direct private procurement from farmers, as well as contract farming, has opened the door for such corporate procurement systems in food grains. As a result, the last change noted above – increased speculation – is already visible. For instance, Chand (2007) found that the sharp rise in wheat prices in 2007 could not be attributed to a general shortfall, as production fell by less than 1% that year (as compared to a 13% rise in prices). He identifies two other causes for the price rise: a climb in international wheat prices, which under trade liberalisation are reflected in Indian prices, and private procurement by Reliance, Cargill, ITC and a few other corporates. Private corporate procurement essentially consisted of paying a slightly higher price to farmers than the official minimum support price, buying grains in bulk and then engaging in speculation on wheat prices. The most immediate lesson is that “efficient” corporate supply chains do not necessarily mean lower end prices; they can in fact mean the opposite. The coupling of the spreading of corporate retail with the steady decline in the public distribution system can only exacerbate such developments.
In food processing, the government has attempted to expand the processing industry in the country for reasons of crop diversification and employment generation. But the expansion of this sector is hindered by a lack of access to credit, lengthy supply chains and low demand for processed foods (EPW 2003; EPW 2005). Low demand in turn is a function of the high availability of fresh foods (Sidhu 2005). In this context, corporate retail is held to be a key requirement of strengthening the food processing industry, because it is expected to drive up demand for processed food products (see for instance Mukherjee and Patel 2005).
But corporate food systems are likely to have their own consequences for the food processing industry. The impact of increased contract farming has already been discussed in the previous section. As for employment generation, consolidation would likely displace small unorganized sector processors, who currently provide 86.8% of employment in the sector (Dev and Rao 2005). Such a trend could only be countered by a very large expansion in demand for processed goods. But as Sidhu (2005) points out, demand for processed foods is limited not just by the lack of investment, but by the sheer inability of most of the population to even purchase their own staple diets – leave alone processed foods.
Corporate Retail
This finally brings us to the most discussed area, namely corporate retailers themselves. Initially, such retailers tend to penetrate only into urban upper class segments, especially given the higher prices that most corporate retail outlets charge when the corporate food system has not yet been set up. However, this soon changes, and corporate retailers penetrate well into the markets of the poor and into smaller towns (Reardon et al 2003), though there remains a correlation between education, income levels, type of employment and use of supermarkets (Hu et al 2004; Faiguenbaum et al 2002). There are also sectoral patterns in the expansion of corporate retailers. Initial penetration tends to occur with “processed, dry and packaged foods such as noodles, milk products and grains” (Reardon et al 2003). In these sectors, the corporate food system can be consolidated more quickly and with less investment. Penetration into fruits and vegetables remains much more difficult, partly because corporate retailers are perceived as less fresh than daily markets (see for instance Cadilhon et al 2006), and because corporate retailers tend to be more expensive in this segment. Studies showed corporate retailers' fruit and vegetable prices were 10% higher in Thailand (Shepard 2005); 14% higher in Argentina in the 1990's, though this was falling (Ghezan et al 2002); and 10% higher in Vietnam (Hagen 2002).
Contrary to the claims of many corporate retail advocates, expansion of corporate retail has had a clear and major negative impact on other existing retailers. Examples include a 30% decline in small stores in Argentina during the period of corporate retail expansion (Gutman 2002); a 20% decline in traditional food and beverage retailers in Chile in just four years (Faiguenbaum et al 2002); and a fall of 27.8% of market share for street markets in fruits and vegetables and 53.3% for open air dairy markets in Brazil (Farina 2002). In a different context, in the US, the expansion of Wal Mart has been found to be correlated with poverty at the county level, a result that the authors ascribe to the displacement of local stores and consequent “destruction of local leadership capacity” (Goetz and Swaminathan 2004).
In India, available data also shows a significant impact on non-corporate retailers. Kalhan (2007) found that 71% of the shops near a large corporate retailer had shown declines in profits. The ICRIER survey reported a 22.8% decline in profits for nearby small retailers in the first year after a corporate retail outlet opened. The study seeks to argue that this impact “diminishes over time”, but this claim is based not on any time series study of outlets, but instead by comparing units near older corporate retailers with those near more recent ones. This amounts to comparing incomparable data sets. Moreover it only stands to reason that retailers who managed to survive would show a reduced decline, if only because of reduced overall profits (as for instance was the case in Argentina [Gutman 2002]). The ICRIER study's only estimate of the number of retailers who closed is based on the highly unreliable method of asking current retailers about how many outlets they could remember having closed. Moreover, even if one accepts this ostensible trend, there is no reason to believe it would remain so as corporate retailers expand beyond their present miniscule market share, especially given the evidence from other countries.
Where they do accept such decline, advocates of corporate retail tend to explain it as a result of the ostensibly greater convenience of corporate retailers and the lower prices that they offer. But in reality, there does not appear to be international data showing a pattern of consistent and significantly lower prices from corporate retailers. Further, the convenience argument applies largely to those who have private transport – i.e. cars – and access to a refrigerator (Hu et al 2004).
More importantly, this argument ignores the structural factors that greatly favour corporate retailers. Firstly, corporates, especially multinationals, enjoy much easier access to capital and credit than street vendors and small retailers, and at much lower interest rates. India's recent real estate boom has also eased access to speculative capital for mall building and similar activities. Prior to the financial crisis, in 2005, corporate retailers' stocks were trading at price to earnings ratios of 50, more than three times the average ratio of 15 (Kota 2005). Allowing FDI into retail would increase these disparities.
Secondly, access to space and resources is extremely unequal. Urban agencies in India have consistently prioritised allocation of space and construction for the residences of the rich, failing to allocate space for commercial activities and for housing for the poor. The vast majority of urban non-corporate retailers operate in an illegal or semi-legal fashion, discouraging investment while incurring high costs in the form of payoffs to authorities. A study in Mumbai found that hawkers paid an estimated Rs. 324 crores per year as bribes (Da Cunha 2000). Periodic eviction drives in recent years destroy invested capital of small retailers and drive them out of business, as in the sealing drive in Delhi and in “Operation Sunshine” in Kolkata, when an estimated one lakh hawkers were allegedly evicted in a single night (Bhowmik 2000). In contrast, while corporate retailers may also face high real estate costs, legal hurdles are far easier for them to clear. Policies may even be altered in their favour, as in the now famous case where the Supreme Court and the Delhi government allowed six malls to go ahead in Vasant Kunj despite the fact that they lacked clearances (at precisely the same time as the sealing drive in the rest of the city).
Thirdly, corporate retailers' access to capital and to the corporate food system allow them to engage in expansion strategies that are impossible for smaller retailers. One such strategy is promotions, discounts and specials, which smaller retailers cannot afford – and the costs of which, in a particularly crude example of risk transfer, are often imposed on the producers or processors in the corporate supply chain (see Oxfam 2004; Shepard 2005 for international examples). Discounts in general are a key attraction of corporate retailers, reflect control over producers, the ability to speculate on demand, and “loss leader” strategies where one product is used to draw customers into the store (Fine 1996). Whole discount stores are another such strategy, where all products are priced very cheaply, reflecting the ability of the larger corporate to absorb very low margins (or losses) in order to penetrate neighborhoods (see Rodriguez et al 2002; Gutman 2002 for Argentina). Finally, corporates may also use straightforward predatory below cost pricing, as Wal Mart has often been accused of. But it is important to recognise that pricing flexibility does not always mean such blatant predatory pricing, and it can be notoriously difficult to apply legal measures against such activities.
What appears to be lower prices in Indian corporate retailers may often be such price flexibility in operation, a point that the ICRIER study ignores when mapping consumer savings in corporate retail outlets (Joseph et al 2008). Indeed, the same study finds that all the corporate retailers in its case study list “value” and “low prices” as among their market penetration strategies. There is no reason to believe that such low prices will continue after such penetration is complete, excepting if there is large-scale competition between corporate retailers. But such competition is not the experience of industrial nations; as Fine (1996) puts it, competition between corporate retailers in the UK is often about “site wars” - access to the correct area of real estate which allows a maximum consumer base, within which the retailer often enjoys a de facto monopoly or oligopoly situation.
In short, corporate and non-corporate retailers are competing on what is very far from a level playing field. This tends to push existing non-corporate retailers into “niche” markets, such as organic foods, speciality stores, convenient locations, or being open for 24 hours (Rodriguez et al 2002). However, the general pressure on other retailers from corporate retail also inherently makes these strategies more difficult. For instance, while the ability to offer credit is cited as an advantage of non-corporate retailers, in practice data from both Asia and Latin America show that they are increasingly unable to do so due to their own financial pressures (Shepard 2005; Faiguenbaum et al 2002). A survey in Costa Rica found that only 17% of urban customers received credit from small retailers (Reardon and Berdegue 2002). There is no doubt, moreover, that such “niche” markets cannot accommodate anything more than a small proportion of existing non-corporate retailers. It is no one's case that all small retailers will be wiped out; but it is equally unlikely that the majority will not be severely impacted.
Finally, it is also often claimed that even such closure of small retailers will not affect employment. The ICRIER study makes this claim in part on the basis of its finding that there was only a small decrease in employment in non-corporate retailers. But this overlooks the fact that, as Kalhan (2007) points out, most small retailers rely heavily on family labour, which by definition cannot be retrenched. Moreover, such retailers strongly resist actual closure even at extremely low levels of revenue, as retail is their only livelihood. Apparent statistical findings in this regard, in addition to ignoring the rapid spread of these effects as corporate retail expands, can easily mask the actual impoverishment that is occurring. Moreover, the claims of “economic dynamism” generating massive new employment have a tired ring to them, after two decades of 'jobless growth' which has been endlessly accompanied by similar slogans.
Conclusion
The implication of the argument presented here is that expansion of corporate food systems will not only not produce many of their claimed benefits, but rather may exacerbate many of the most severe problems facing India's economy today. These problems include the agricultural crisis, a decline in land fertility and water availability, a collapse in both urban and rural employment, declining food security, price volatility in essential commodities, and resulting pauperisation and inequality. In addition, the total lack of regulation on growth of corporate retailers in urban areas is leading to skyrocketing demands on water and electricity supplies; it was estimated that merely air conditioning the outlets of the Reliance Fresh chain would require 170 MW of electricity (Navdanya 2007).
It is not our contention that all is well with the existing system of provision. Clearly changes are required, but corporate systems will not bring about those changes. Transformation of the existing system of provision is a much larger issue that will require struggles for more fundamental change in India's political economy. In the interim, policy steps are required both to mitigate the problems existing in the current system and to restrict the damage caused by expansion of corporate food systems. Some possibilities that may be considered are as follows.
First, there should be no move to allow foreign direct investment into the retail sector, and the existing relaxations and recent changes in that regard should be discontinued. In regard to agriculture and food security, there are well known changes that are required, such as strengthening the Food Corporation of India and the PDS systems, requiring private procurement to go through mandis, and channelling public investment to upgrade the mandis and for creation of infrastruture. Further, incentives for contract farming should be withdrawn. Measures should be taken including written registration of all contracts (as provided for in the model APMC Act), with incentives to farmers for registration and penalties for corporates that fail to do so. Strict conditions should be placed on the kinds of contracts that would be valid, including bars on exclusive sale agreements and keeping delays in payment to a maximum of a few days. Clear penalties for speculation and hoarding should also be enforced. Steps to encourage the formation of cooperatives and to strengthen the existing cooperative arrangements should be intensified, and public investment focused on cold chain infrastructure provision for such cooperatives.
Existing corporate retailers should be regulated through licensing arrangements run by the local elected bodies, as well as through strict regulations on predatory pricing. Caps on the number of corporate retailers and numbers of similar outlets would also be required. Taxation for additional infrastructure and proportionate cost pricing for electricity, water, space and road use should be levied on such outlets, and the additional revenues used for provision of common areas and credit to small retailers. Non-corporate and small retailers should be granted preferential credit through public funds, and municipal plans altered to provide adequate space for all types of such activities.
These recommendations are discussed in more detail in Sreenivasa (2007), and further are similar to those put forward in the Left Parties' proposed National Policy on Retail. It is our belief that a critical debate on such measures is long overdue in India's policy discourse. The evidence is overwhelmingly against the view that corporate systems' problems will be addressed through benign self-regulation (as proposed by ICRIER), a massive expansion in the retail market, and “enlightened” public assistance. Our economy today needs steps to protect, enhance and defend the livelihoods of the majority, not policies that promote the super profits of a few.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
[Some of these arguments are explored in greater detail in Sreenivasa (2007) below. The authors are grateful to the Council for Social Development for supporting the research used in this article.]
Bhowmik, Sharit R. (2000). “A raw deal?”, Seminar, June.
Cadilhon, Jean-Joseph; Moustier, Paule; Poole, Nigel D.; Tam, Phan Thi Giac; Feame, Andrew P. (2006) “Traditional vs. Modern Food Systems? Insights from Vegetable Supply Chains to Ho Chi Minh City (Vietnam)”, Development Policy Review, 24:1.
Chandrasekhar, C.P., and Ghosh, Jayati (2003). “Is Corporate Farming Really the Solution for Indian Agriculture?”, Business Line, December 16.
Bharadwaj, Krishna (1985). “A view on commercialisation in Indian agriculture and the development of capitalism”, Journal of Peasant Studies 12, no. 4: 7.
Byres, Terence J., (2003). “Agriculture and Development: the Dominant Orthodoxy and an Alternative View”, in H-J. Chang (ed) Rethinking Development Economics (London: Anthem Press) Chapter 11.
Chauhan, Sarita (2006). “FDI in Retail: Bane or Boon”, SSRN Paper. New Delhi: Confederation of Indian Industry, June.
da Cunha, Gerson (2000). “Steering Clear of Icebergs”, Seminar, June.
Daftari, Irshad (2006). “Contract farming lures India Inc biggies”, Economic Times, May 8.
Dev, Mahendra S. and Chandrashekhar Rao, N. (2005) “Food Processing and Contract Farming in Andhra Pradesh: A Small Farmer Perspective”, Economic and Political Weekly, June 25.
Economic and Political Weekly (EPW) (2003). “Food Processing: Unrealised Potential”, Economic and Political Weekly, July 19.
Economic and Political Weekly (EPW) (2005). “Food Processing: More Recommendations”, Economic and Political Weekly, January 15.
Faiguenbaum, Sergio; Berdegue, Julio A.; Reardon, Thomas (2002). “The Rapid Rise of Supermarkets in Chile: Effects on Dairy, Vegetable and Beef Chains”, Development Policy Review, Vol 20:4.
Farina, Elizabeth M.M.Q (2002). “Consolidation, Multinationalisation and Competition in Brazil: Impacts on Horticulture and Dairy Products Systems”, Development Policy Review, Vol 20:4.
Fine, Ben and Leopold, Ellen (1993). The World of Consumption (London: Routledge).
Fine, Ben (1996). “From Political Economy to Consumption”, in D. Miller (ed) Acknowledging Consumption (London: Routledge).
Fine, Ben (2002). The World of Consumption: Second Edition (London: Routledge).
Ghezan, Graciela; Mateos, Monica; Viteri, Laura (2002). “Impact of Supermarkets and Fast Food Chains on Horticultural Supply Chains in Argentina”, Development Policy Review, Vol 20:4.
Goetz, Stephan J. and Swaminathan, Hema (2004). “Wal-Mart and County Wide Poverty”, AERS Staff Paper No. 371, Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology, The Pennsylvania State University, October 18.
Gutman, Graciela (2002). “Impact of the Rapid Rise of the Supermarket System on Dairy Products Systems in Argentina”, Development Policy Review, Vol. 20:4.
Hagen, James M. (2002). “Causes and Consequences of Food Retail Innovation in Developing Countries: Supermarkets in Vietnam”, Working Paper. Ithaca, ?
Hu, Dinghuan; Reardon, Thomas; Rozelle, Scott; Timmer, Peter; and Wang, Honglin (2004). “The Emergence of Supermarkets With Chinese Characteristics: Challenges and Opportunities for China's Agricultural Development”, Development Policy Review, Vol 22:5.
Joseph, Mathew, Nirupama Soundararajan, Manisha Gupta, and Sanghamitra Sahu (2008). "Impact of Organized Retailing on the Unorganised Sector". Working Paper 222, Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations (ICRIER), September.
Kalhan, Anuradha (2007). “Impact of Malls on Small Shops and Hawkers”, Economic and Political Weekly, June 2.
Kota, Radha (2005). “WSJ: Investor Enthusiasm Keeps Indian Retail Shares Expensive”, posted online at india.seekingalpha.com. Last accessed on February 1, 2007.
Kumar, Vijay, Yogesh Patwari, and Ayush H N. (2008). “Organised Food Retailing: A Blessing or a Curse,” Economic and Political Weekly, May 17.
Mukherjee, Arpita and Patel, Nitisha (2005). FDI in Retail Sector: India (New Delhi: Department of Consumer Affairs, Ministry of Consumer Affairs, Food and Public Distribution; and Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations).
Navdanya (2007). “Social, environmental and economic consequences of corporate retail”, Press Release. Available at www.navdanya.org, last accessed on May 2, 2007.
Oxfam (2004). Trading Away Our Rights: Women in Global Supply Chains (Oxford: Oxfam).
Sharma, Devender (2004). “Towards a Grey Revolution?”, IndiaTogether.org, February. Available online at www.indiatogether.org, last accessed on December 25, 2008.
Reardon, Thomas and Berdegue, Julio A. (2002). “The Rapid Rise of Supermarkets in Latin America: Challenges and Opportunities for Development”, Development Policy Review, Vol. 20:4.
Reardon, Thomas; Timmer, C. Peter; Barrett, Christopher B.; Berdegue, Julio (2003). “The Rise of Supermarkets in Africa, Asia and Latin America”, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 85:5.
Rodriguez, Elsa; Berges, Miriam; Casellas, Karina; Di Paola, Rosangela; Lupin, Beatriz; Garrido, Laura; and Gentile, Natacha (2002). “Consumer Behavior and Supermarkets in Argentina”, Development Policy Review, Vol 20:4.
Shepard, Andrew W. (2005). “The implications of supermarket development for horticultural farmers and traditional marketing systems in Asia." Paper presented to FAO Regional Workshop, Kuala Lumpur.
Sidhu, M.S. (2005). “Fruit and Vegetable Processing in India: An Appraisal of the Post Reform Period”, Economic and Political Weekly, July 9.
Singh, S.P. (2005). “Agriculture”, in Alternative Survey Group, Disequalising Growth: Alternative Economic Survey, India, 2004-2005 (New Delhi: Daanish Books).
Sreenivasa, Priya (2007). Markets vs. Markets: The Consequences of Corporate Retail and Allowing Foreign Direct Investment in the Retail Sector (New Delhi: Council for Social Development)
[1] See for instance Faigenbaum et al 2002, Ghezan et al 2002, Fritschel 2003, Shepard 2005, Boselie et al 2004, Cadilhon et al 2006 and Oxfam 2004 for other parts of the world, and Chandrasekhar and Ghosh 2003 for India.
[2] See for instance Byres 2003, Bharadwaj 1985. By the term productive cultivators, we are excluding rentier and absentee Landlords
THOUGHT OF THE DAY
Success is doing something when you have nothing else to do.
Rosie Cash